Impact of the FairTax(SM) on Investment
Investment is important to all wage earners because of the relationship that exists between real wage rates and the level of capital investment per worker. In fact, the most significant contributing factor to achieving higher, real wages is the level of capital investment per worker. A worker or farmer, for example, is more productive if he has more machinery and equipment to work with, particularly new equipment that incorporates the latest technological innovations. Higher productivity leads to higher real wages. Employers cannot pay workers higher wages than their productivity justifies without jeopardizing their businesses. Higher investment levels per hour worked explain as much as 97 percent of the increase in inflation-adjusted wages since 1948, as can be seen in Figure 1.[1] FIGURE
1: This figure shows the positive correlation between real
wage rates and capital investment per hours worked, from 1947 to 1992.
During this time period, the amount of capital per hour worked increased
steadily
Replacing the current tax system with the FairTax would eliminate the tax bias against investment. Harvard economist Dale Jorgenson estimates that, after implementation of the sales tax, yearly real investment would initially increase by 80 percent relative to the investment that would be made under present law. Jorgenson's research shows that this increase would gradually decline over the period of a decade to 20 percent.[2] Boston University economist Laurence Kotlikoff also predicts an investment boom. Measuring the change in the size of the overall capital invested (rather than annual investment), he predicts that within 10 years total invested capital will be 17 percent larger than it would be under the present tax system.[3] The higher productivity caused by more investment per worker is one of the few ways to make U.S. goods more competitive while maintaining high living standards. The U.S. has lower rates of capital formation and a lower savings rate than most of its major trading partners, including Japan, Germany, France, the Netherlands, Italy and Canada.[4] Although domestic capital investment is a leading factor influencing wage rates, it is not the only factor. Foreign capital investment will also positively impact domestic wage rates and our economy. After repeal of the income tax, the U.S. will be perhaps the most attractive place on earth to invest. The U.S. will attract investment capital from around the world that will finance new plants and create jobs here in America. U.S. workers will build these plants, much of the equipment installed in the plants will be American made, and American workers will be employed in these plants to produce goods for both domestic and foreign markets. Additionally, expatriated U.S. investment dollars can also be expected to find their way home. In all, during the 1980's when marginal tax rates were reduced in the U.S. from a top rate of 70 percent down to 28 percent, the U.S. attracted a net capital inflow of roughly one-half trillion dollars.[5] Given the proposed tax treatment, strong infrastructure, political stability, relatively sound legal institutions, large domestic market and educated workforce in the U.S., investment in the U.S. will be singularly attractiveto the benefit of U.S. industry, U.S. workers and U.S. consumers. [1] "The Truth About Falling Wages," Gary and Aldona Robbins, p. 5, Institute for Policy Innovation, 3rd Quarter, 1995. [2] Dale W. Jorgenson, Harvard University, "The Impact of Taxing Consumption," Testimony before the Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, March 27, 1996. [3] Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Boston University, Testimony before the Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, June 6, 1995. See also, "The Economic Impact of Replacing Federal Income Taxes with a Sales Tax," Laurence J. Kotlikoff, April 15, 1993, Cato Institute. [4] Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1999, Table 1365, p. 843. [5] See, "The ABCs of the Capital Gains Tax," Stephen Moore and John Silvia, October 4, 1995, the Cato Institute, pp. 1617.
|